Would you like to close a narrow subsidy benefiting the paper
industry and have the Koch brothers kick in a few bucks to subsidize
your shiny new insurance policy you purchased on the exchanges?
Perhaps you’d like to see Ted Cruz and Goldman Sachs
negotiate how to split a $5,000 tax increase that will help expand Medicaid?
If you answered “yes” to either of those questions, you’re
in luck – the Affordable Care Act does both.
(Maybe the next round of reforms can get the corporate jet
loophole – we’ll keep working on it)
Follow me below the fold for a rundown of some of the major
tax loopholes the ACA closes to help fund it. As always, numbers come from the
Joint Committee on Taxation and much of the inspiration and analysis comes from
John McDonough.
The first loophole closure is actually an excise tax, but it
functions to considerably narrow the exemption of employer-provided health
insurance offerings.
Unlike regular wages, which are subjected to both payroll
and income taxes, employer-provided health insurance is compensation that is
tax free. There are two particular tax
benefits. First, any employer contribution is tax-free compensation. Second,
any employee use pretax dollars to pay for contributions to premiums or a health
savings account. Both essentially function as large tax deductions that generally
benefit more well-off people. The higher
position you hold, the more likely it is that you have access to an employer
plan, the more generous that plan is likely to be, and the more likely it is
that an employer will pay for all of the costs. Take our dear friend Sen. Cruz, whose family is covered gold-plated health plan worth up to $40,000 paid for by his wife’s employer, Goldman Sachs.
(Compare that to the annual premium value of a standard Premier Care plan at the
University of Michigan, which runs $16,932 and is a quite good value).
Economists fear that these tax-free plans create incentives
for employers to put money into health benefits and not wages,
disproportionately favoring investments in health care, which in turn leads to
overspending on health care and excess care and inflation in the health sector.
The idea is that placing an excise tax on plans in excess of
a certain threshold (slated to start at $10,000 for an individual and $27,500
for families in 2018), will force employers to re-evaluate how they compensate
their employees. Goldman Sachs would owe roughly $5,000 on Cruz’s family plan,
which they no doubt would offload part of on the employee . (Note, that this
representation isn’t exactly correct, because the ACA regulations in question
actually define the tax value of a plan differently than it’s raw premium cost,
but you get the idea)
The tax also broadly redistributes benefits from people who
have excessive health insurance to those who don’t have any and will benefit
from subsidies on the exchanges or enroll in Medicaid.
So far, so good: We’ve raised Ted Cruz’s taxes (indirectly
because the excise tax would fall on Goldman-Sachs, but it still feels
satisfying). So why are many progressives worried about this tax?
As it turns out, they have several very real concerns.
First, many of the most expensive plans actually belong to
small businesses, who have small insurance pools and can’t spread their risk
over large numbers of employees. Ditto
for employers whose employee pool consists of older, sicker, more female or
high risk professionals (like firefighters).
The structure of the ACA does mitigate some of those risks,
by allowing adjustments for high risk professions and giving small business
owners access to the broad risk pools of the exchanges, while banning discrimination
based on gender and limiting it for age. It also delays the onset of the tax to
2018 to allow employers to adjust, and unions with strong health plans to
renegotiate contracts.
Assuming those things go smoothly (which is a big assumption)
the tax is a win-win. If it ends up biting some health-insurance plans, it
means that the proceeds will fund people who don’t have health insurance. If
Cadillac plans get renegotiated to the point where they stay under the taxable threshold,
it means that health care inflation is slowing drastically.
Indeed, slowing increases in health insurance inflation has
already led the CBO to downgrade projected revenue from the excise tax.
Loophole II: Narrowing Cellulosic Biofuels Provider Credit ($27
billion)
Yes, ethanol tax credits even made their way into health
reform (kind of). This closes a loophole
opened by a 2009 IRS ruling indicated that certain unprocessed wood byproducts
called “black liquor” (really) used to power some paper plants. Democrats
wanted to close this loophole and used the savings to help pay for the ACA. So
when you get your new exchange policy, send Georgia Pacific or your favorite
paper manufacturer a thank-you note because a couple of bucks of your subsidy
came from them. I’m sure the Koch brothers will appreciate it.
UPDATE: This provision was repealed in 2011.
Are you seeing the theme here? (Yes, elections DO make a big
difference, don't they?)
Loophole IV: adjustments to Health Savings Accounts, tax
deductions for medical care and Flexible Spending Arrangements ($33 billion)
This group of changes limits tax-deductible contributions to
HSAs FSAs to $2,500 and limits the definition of medical services that can be paid
for with HSAs for FSAs. HSAs and FSAs
allow people to save pretax dollars to pay for medical expenses. Since
working-class people generally live paycheck to paycheck and can’t save much
money, they generally can’t take advantage. Other changes increase the floor
for tax deductions for medical expenses.
So adding up here, we get approximately $110 billion in
additional tax revenue from the well-off to fund access to health care for
poor, working-class and middle class Americans through the end of the decade.
That’s about 11 percent of the costs of Obamacare during that time.
Check in tomorrow for the final installment when I examine budget cuts.
No comments:
Post a Comment